[page 1]
CHANGING
NAME-TAGS
A
LEGAL ANTHROPOLOGICAL APPROACH TO
COMMUNAL LANDS IN PORTUGAL[1]
Roland Brouwer
Introduction
The issue of common property regimes inspires a worldwide debate on property and natural resource management. Most contributions to this debate address directly or indirectly Hardin’s (1968) challenging article on the “tragedy of the commons”. Three major lines can be discerned. One consists of attempts to prove that Hardin’s concepts and models are flawed. Berkes et al. (1989) and Feeny et al. (1990) for example, stress that Hardin confuses common property with open access situations. F. von Benda-Beckmann (1995) points to the lack of congruence in Hardin’s analogy between overpopulation, related to the private rights to sexual intercourse and procreation, and communal grazings. The second line of criticism consists of case material on ‘comedies of the commons’: reports of successful (meaning sustainable) resource management by and on behalf of communities (e.g., Cox 1985; Acheson 1988; various contributions to McCay and Acheson 1987). The third line is composed of articles that expose defects of alternative property regimes. Fife (1977) demonstrates that it may be economically perfectly rational for a private owner to prefer extermination of a natural resource to conservation, on the basis of maximizing profit. Hardin (1979) himself shows that planting slow-growing tree species like the californian redwoods is an uneconomic use of land for private investors.
By definition, property should be a central concept of any debate on common
property-rights regimes. Strangely enough, most contributions to that debate
lack [page 2] a systematic and thorough analysis of this concept. They remain confined to
a highly schematic division of property-rights regimes into four mutually
exclusive categories: open access, state, communal and private property (e.g., Ostrom 1990; Bromley 1992; Acheson 1994; Hanna, Folke and Mäler 1996). This
simplified or ‘thin’ categorisation having been made, property is taken for
granted and seen as self-evident. However, certain case studies indicate that
the lines that divide these categories are less clear than the model suggests.
Property-rights regimes may take new forms according to economic, demographic or
political conditions. The Tigray described by Bauer (1987) change their tenure
system from an inclusive communal into an exclusive private-hereditary model and
vice versa according to economic conditions and demographic pressure. In
response to governmental disentitling policies, villagers in Portugal and Spain
formally divided their commons into private plots while maintaining in practice
the communal use form the government policies sought to abolish (Rodrigues 1987;
Brouwer 1995b: 149-150; Galilea 1998). These examples indicate that the property
form can be flexible in response to internal dynamics or external impositions.
They also indicate that the outside property form may not correspond to social
relations and forms of resource use underneath. Apparently, the property
categories that dominate in common property discourse are not as clear-cut and
mutually exclusive as they appear at first sight (Berkes 1996; McCay 1996).
Property is a concept that covers a wide variety of social relations. The ‘thin’
approach currently dominating the debate impedes a correct understanding of the
ways in which people are part of property relations. As a result of the
superficial treatment of property, the debate on common property issues remains
shallow. It produces overarching models that are ‘suspended’ from social reality
and pay insufficient attention to cultural and historical specificity. To
overcome this limitation, McCay (1996) and McCay and Jentoft (1998) call for
‘thick’ descriptions of specific property relations. Thick descriptions produce
“a stratified hierarchy of meaningftul structures” in terms of which concrete
actions “are produced, perceived and interpreted” (Geertz 1973). They consist of
a “careful specification of property rights and systems of resource use and
their embeddetiness within discrete and changing historical moments” (McCay and
Jentoft 1998).
The superficial treatment of property renders the common property regime debate
shallow. A similar conclusion can be drawn with regard to the debate’s second
central concept: community. Community is a problematic notion in itself. It is
difficult to delineate a community. Is a family household a community? And what
about a corporation, or the totality of the citizens of a certain state? In this
paper I shall not attempt to answer these difficult questions, but to address
another related issue. As Li (1996) argues on the basis of the Philippine common
[page 3] property debate, in the common literature communities seem to be equated to a
certain ideal-typical village. Inequalities within commoners’ communities remain
unattended to (e.g., Cox 1985; Acharya 1989; for a critique, see Brouwer
1995a). This approach reflects the fact that most of the literature on common
property arrangements confines itself to the two-dimensional space defined by
the pairs community-state and community-market. The common property resource
debate is largely caged in a nostalgic discourse revolving around the desire to
retain the remnants of the organic social relations of the (ideal-type)
Gemeinschaft in a contractually organised (ideal-type) Gesellschaft
characterized by commodification, abstraction and alienation (e.g., Dias 1983,
1984; Cox 1985; Ribeiro 1991; Jodha 1996; Ostrom and Schlager 1996). It stands
in the powerful tradition within post-enlightenment thinking that counterposes a
harmonious community to cruel capitalism (Li 1996).
The idealization of commons-managing communities is partly the result of the
policy agenda of many of the debate’s participants. Images of successful
resource-managing communities are used to advocate a shift of resource control
away from the State and private capital to the rural people whose livelihoods
depend most directly upon those resources (Li 1996: 504). Within political
struggles, as elsewhere, for example within the framework of judicial trials or
court cases, an idealized image is considered a more effective weapon than a
detailed account that may include aspects that run counter to the case one wants
to defend.
It may be justifiable from a political advocacy perspective to present
simplified images of social life and discard its complexities, although, in my
opinion, ultimately social movements are better off with a solid analysis than
with an image that only provides a partial understanding of the reality they act
in and want to change. From an academic point of view, no justification exists
for this type of simplification. The models developed within academia should not
be ‘suspended’ from but ‘grounded’ in reality through an intimate link to the
collected data (Glaser and Strauss 1967). They should elucidate the complex
social interactions they are supposed to represent and make visible the
structures that underlie these social practices.
The subject matter of this paper is the communal land issue in Portugal.
However, I have no intention of advocating common property arrangements per
Se. Instead, I want to contribute to the ‘thick’ mode of analysis called fur
by McCay and Jentoft (1998) through a thorough analysis of property, its fonns
as specified by the adjectives public, common, private, etc., the contextual and
historical dimension of its contents, and the relevance of property labels for
social struggles. For this aim the paper relies on a legal anthropological
approach that combines a juridical view on property with an ethnographic study
[page 4] of the processes of rule and norm
production, reproduction and enforcement concerning property at different levels
within societies.
The paper starts with a short discussion of the basic concepts and approach. Then it continues with an elaboration of the legal aspects of the commons in Portugal. It shows that there is a difference between popular and legal speech over the commons, and that within the legal sphere different names and understandings as to concrete sets of property rights evolved. The notions mentioned in these sections come alive in the third part, which describes and analyzes a conflict between two communities over certain tracts of land. One Community claims land as its commons, whereas another maintains that it is its parish land. In the last section the paper returns to its starting point by contrasting a ‘thin’ with a ‘thick’ analysis of the case.
Law as a Social Phenomenon
Property is a legal concept, with a long history within different legal traditions, which as far as relevant to this paper will be discussed later. Yet the property concept cannot be understood if one limits oneself to a law-centred approach. For property is also a social phenomenon, consisting of the relations among people over resources. The powers of a proprietor over his property are always dependent on wider social relationships. These powers exist only if they are socially accepted, and recognized and defended by the society of which the proprietor is part. On the other hand, society always puts certain constraints on rights of user, so that property is never absolute or complete. Any form of property (state, common, private) has a societal or communal dimension to it, which enables and protects the proprietor and constrains him.
The study of law as a social phenomenon has developed within the field of legal anthropology. Roughly speaking, one may say that within legal anthropology two different currents exist. The first is the older and perhaps in terms of volume produced the most important. This current consists of authors such as Bohannan (1967), Pospisil (1967, 1971), Redfield (1967), and Gluckman (1969), who try to distil law from primitive societies. Through the identification of abstract norms or through case studies of conflicts, they attempt to determine whether within a certain society law exists and, if it does, what it can be considered to consist of. My paper should be located in the second approach within legal anthropology. This is less interested in tracing or constructing ‘native’ law than in understanding how nonnative frameworks, i.e. law, are part of social life. The subject-matter of this type of study is rule making, bending and eluding in the interaction between different social agents. Examples are Moore (1973, 1978), K. von Benda-Beckmann (1981), and F. von Benda-Beckmann and Van [page 5] der Velde (1992).
An important consequence of acknowledging that law is a social phenomenon is the notion that law is part of social struggles. Laws are not produced in a social vacuum. They are political statements, shaped by the aspirations and normative conceptions of those who have been able to influence their formulation. Chanock (1982) provides a colourful image of the way in which male aspirations for power over women in combination with a Victorian conception of gender relations conduced to a so-called ‘traditional’ legal system favouring male over female interests in marital disputes. His article shows that the production of rules (laws) is never innocent. A similar conclusion can be drawn from the way in which in Portugal laws have treated the concept of common property (Brouwer 1995b; see also below).
In principle it would be possible to study the common property concept exclusively as a legal phenomenon. Such a law-centred approach would recognize insufficiently the social nature of law. In a law-centred approach, law appears as a self-consistent body of rules, which are produced by the State and are, to an extent that depends on the nature of the political regime, an expression of a volonté general or general will (Spiertz and Wiber 1996). The recognition that law is intimately connected to the State’s real and claimed powers, however, requires that one analyzes the State and the political field. The State, which itself is divided, is both the arena and the stake in social struggles for political power, dominance, and the realisation of particular interests (Jessop 1983). These multiple ambitions, interests and struggles produce inconsistent and diverse texts with multiple interpretations. Moreover, even within clearly defined polities such as the European states, the State is not the sole source of rules. There is ‘legal pluralism’ even here. Local bodies, communities, guilds, the Church, different societal fields (so-called ‘semi-autonomous fields’) all produce rules with a strong normative power over those for whom they are designed, and these are sometimes backed up by the central State’s juridical apparatus. Consequently, law is rarely coherent and mostly inconsistent (see: Bohannan 1967; Pospisil 1971; Moore 1978, Galanter 1981; Merry 1988; Griffiths 1986, 1991; F. von Benda-Beckmann 1991; Brouwer 1992; Spiertz 1992; Li 1996; Spiertz and Wiber 1996).
The acknowledgement of legal pluralism has helped the understanding of several aspects of law and power: the ‘gap’ problem (Nelken 1981); ‘legal cannibalism’ (Spiertz 1992) exemplified by municipal laws that predate the State and are absorbed by the State or inediatisiert (Van den Bergh 1996); the autonomy of society vis-à-vis the State; and the existence of room for manoeuvre within the normative field for social movements that seek to contest state power and legitimacy (Brouwer 1995b).
[page 6]
In his critique of legal pluralism, Tamanaha (1993) argues that its proponents over-stretch the term law. He contends that that concept should remain reserved for State-produced norms of conduct. I agree that over-stretching concepts only blurs our perception of reality. However, Tamanaha’s criticism does not deny the main point entailed in the concept of legal pluralism: the production of politically significant rules and rule enforcement outside the State apparatus. This will be illustrated by the case-study of the collapse of communal land use arrangements in Northern Portugal that forms the core of this article.
The Property Concept
The above discussion has profound consequences for an understanding of the concept of property. Viewing law as malleable, inconsistent and the outcome of, and object at stake in ongoing struggles within society (F. von Benda-Beckmann 1992, 1995; Spiertz and Wiber 1996), and more particularly within the political field (Brouwer 1 995b), automatically leads to an approach in which property is no longer an overarching and self-evident notion. Instead, it emerges as a container that constantly receives new contents and new labels from different actors who, in the course of the various social struggles in which they are involved, refer to different normative frameworks before different fora, in different ‘rooms’, and within different sections of society (F. von Benda-Beckmann 1995). Actors ‘shop’ for forum and idiom. Within their culturally, socially, economically and politically limited fields of choice, they select an idiom and a room to obtain the most favourable outcome (K. von Benda-Beckmann 1981; Spiertz 1991).
The contents of the property container are often summarized by the phrase ‘bundle of rights’ (e.g., Hanna, Folke and Maler 1996; Ostrom and Schlager 1996). The idea of a bundle of rights is borrowed from the Common Law system (Maine 1883 quoted by K. von Benda-Beckmann 1995; Stein and Shand 1974 quoted by Van den Bergh 1988: 80-81; Van den Bergh 1996). It expresses an understanding of property as a combination of different capacities (strands) of an individual or a group of individuals to exploit a resource, to regulate access and use by exclusion, admission and direction of other users, and to derive rents from his own use or from by use by others. (Ostrom and Schlager [1996: 1331 provide a schematic overview of different bundles of rights.) Each strand refers to a single right over a single resource, so that the reach of an actual property right depends on the combination of strands contained in the bundle. Because property is a social phenomenon, this is historically determined. Thus the bundle’s composition is malleable.
In addition to a content, the bundle has a label or name tag. This label may be [page 7] summarized by the words state, common, private, or others. It is important that these name-tags, although contingent on the content, may or may not cover the content. Moreover, the content itself is both resource and stake in social struggle. Under certain conditions, it may be useful to present a certain combination of entitlements as ‘private’ (e.g., the Portuguese and Spanish villagers mentioned above). In other cases, such as the one described in the rest of this paper, ‘public’ or ‘common’ may be more appropriate.
A ‘thick’ analysis requires the reading of a series of events (in the words of Geertz 1973, a ‘discourse’ or ‘dialogue’)[2] in such a manner that the underlying stratified hierarchy of meaningful structures becomes visible and transparent. This paper attempts to provide such a ‘thick’ analysis of a ‘discourse’ or ‘dialogue’ between inhabitants of a rural area in the north of Portugal. It describes the evolution of the complex combination of entitlements held over time by the different stakeholders involved. It shows that the labels that were strategically tagged to these entitlements were highly relevant to the outcome of the ensuing struggle. At a certain moment, common land is labelled waste land. As a result, it becomes subject to a reclamation policy that entails the liquidation of common property arrangements and the transfer of land to the private or the public domain. In the specific case, local people succeed in tagging another label to the land, that of public (parish) property. Under this label it no longer fits into the category destined for reclamation, and so escapes government interference. This new tag leads to problems between the parish, that now uses it to claim the land as its property, and a part of the commoners, who feel that their rights are being infringed.
The strategic value of these tags is partly shaped by the rights they refer to. Tags and contents are not identical, but they are also not totally independent. Tags referring to specific feudal elements of property lose their legal value whemi it becomes clear that these elements have been formally abolished, but may retain social influence. An interesting feature of the case described in this paper is that phantoms of old, long abolished rights continue to play an important role in present social practices and legal discourse.
[page 8]
One Common, Two Discourses
Communal grazing areas existed all over Europe. In most countries they
disappeared during the profound political and economic changes of the nineteenth
century. In Portugal, these commons remained at least partly intact. Here, about
507,000 ha are communal lands. Most can be found in northern districts such as
Vila Real (Devy-Vareta 1993: 161).
In popular speech the rural population of Vila Real will refer to commons as montes do povo. A literal translation of this term would be ‘the people’s hills’. Indeed, in most cases these commons are situated on highlands. However, in this phrase the word monte does not have the ordinary significance of ‘hill’. Instead, it is etymologically connected to the word montado, which refers to forest pastures and which is still used for the stands of cork and stone oaks in the south of Portugal. The expression monte blanco meant a communal thicket (Neves 1964). In the past, the term montado was also applied to the commons in the north of the country. In the 1515 charter of the municipality of Vila Real, the phrase montado de gado de ora (livestock montado) was used to denote the communal grazing grounds in the area (Arquivo Nacional Torte de Tombo, Casa do Infantado, Livro 215). In 1886, the parish council of Torgueda in the same municipality used monte and inontado as synonyms in its by-laws. Apparently, the popular term does not connect the commons to waste highlands, but to open forest areas.
Whereas in popular language the word monte prevails, in legal and administrative discourses people use the term baldio (plural baldios). This term was first applied as a general denominator for communal land during the eighteenth century. The concept of communal ownership of land, however, is much older. It can be traced back to the period immediately following the conquest of the Iberian peninsula from the Moors, the so-called reconquista, and the foundation of the Portuguese kingdom in the twelfth century. The Crown claimed the dominium directum or dominium eminens over all land in the realm and handed out certain grants to nobles, to the Church and religious orders, and to peasant communities. These grants resulted either in the private appropriation of that land or in its subjection to certain forms of communal exploitation, such as grazing, the collection of brush for fertilizer, and the gathering of wood for construction and fuel. As a result, a situation emerged in which collective rights were exercised on three types of land: land owned by the Crown, land held by nobles or corporations, and land owned by communities (Gralheiro 1990: 24). Hespanha (1980: 219-224) calls this feudal conception of law ‘realist’: it presupposes a general order in which things and men are integrated. The relations between men and things are derived from the functions that these things have or can have in that order (ex parte rei). Each of the alternative uses [page 9] corresponded to a type of appropriation or dominium.
In the eighteenth century the lawyer Tomaz Vila Nova de Portugal reinterpreted earlier royal ordinances. Within the general category of waste lands or baldios, he distinguished maninhos (private land under communal exploitation), bens do concelho (land owned by the municipality), and the logradouros comuns or the ‘true’ baldios, which belonged to the povos (village communities). According to the legal system of these days, povos were communities with a special legal status and autonomy within the municipality. In 1772, a new law explicitly separated these ‘true’ baldios from municipal property (JCI 1939: 1; Velozo 1953: 23-25; Rodrigues 1987: 19-20; Graiheiro 1990: 24-27).
Commons in Portuguese Civil Law
In the nineteenth century legal theorists formulated a new approach to the concept of property. They distinguished between four categories. The first category, res communes, consisted of objects that concerned humanity in general, like the air or the sea. The second, res publicae, was composed of things that pertained to the nation, such as rivers and harbours. The third category, res universitatis, were things that involved only a part of the nation (a community or municipality). For example, theatres, stadiums, and the baldios belonged to this category. The last category, res singulorum, were things that pertained to private individuals. This was identical to private property (Velozo 1953: 26; Soares 1968: 27-31).
This approach had a strong influence on the Civil Code that was enacted in 1867 and maintained for almost a century, until 1966. In articles 379, 380, 381, and 382 a distinction was made between public things, communal things, and private things (coisas ptiblicas, coisas comuns, and coisas particulares). The first and third categories referred to public and private property (res publicae and res singulorum) respectively, whereas the second category referred to communal property, the res universitatis (as something different from shared property or corporate property). Communal property was defined in article 381 as follows:
Communal are natural or artificial things which are not individually appropriated, and of which only the individuals living within a certain administrative circumscription or forming part of a certain public corporation are allowed to take profit within the confines of administrative regulations. (Quoted in Velozo 1953: 28; my translation).
These ‘communal things’ expressly included the baldios. Article 473 equated [page 10] them to ‘any municipal or parochial land’ and incorporated them in the property of municipalities or parishes (Soares 1968: 51). Thus the Civil Code placed the commons within the category of res universitatis and firmly consigned them to the State and its institutions.
However, one should take into account that the establishment of such a legal framework did not automatically imply that the State really controlled the destiny of these commons. The autonomy at a local level of the municipalities, which were older than the state itself, was still large, and in many respects they defended local interests against the central government instead of limiting themselves to the implementation of policy guidelines coming from above. The position of parishes within the state apparatus is even more ambivalent. Parishes were originally ecclesiastical units wherein the Church exercised certain functions that later came to be seen as typically pertaining to public administration (e.g., keeping birth, death and marriage registers). It was not until the administrative code of 1878 that parishes were turned into the lowest level of state administration (Caetano 1991: 352-254; Gralheiro 1990: 32-35). However, like the municipalities, they were not automatically turned by this development into obedient servants. Again, within the parishes central guidelines and local interests could clash, creating a gap between what the central government wanted to happen and what really happened at a local level.
The formal consignment of the commons to the State entailed by the legal theory embodied in the 1867 Civil Code may not have meant that the State acquired full control over the commons, but it accorded with the State’s overall aspirations with regard to the commons. From the end of the eighteenth through the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, the Portuguese governments took various measures to abolish the commons. Reviews by the JCI (1939: 1-12), Rodrigues (1987: 32-48), Gralheiro (1990: 32-36), and Nunes and FeijO (1990: 65-74) demonstrate that there has been a constant tendency in legislation to legitimize or stimulate the privatization of the commons or to promote their transfer to the State. After the downfall of the monarchy in 1910 the new republican regime continued in the same vein. However, it was only after the military coup of 1926 that the State acquired enough power to impose its policy by force. Several measures were taken to promote division, settlement, and afforestation of the coinnions. In 1966 this policy culminated in the exclusion of the concept of communal property from the new Civil Code. As a result, the baldios were included in the private property of the administrative bodies, municipalities, and parishes, although they could still be subjected to certain collective usufructuary rights. As long as these rights were exercised, the law placed certain limits upon the local authorities’ liberty to alienate the land or to allocate it to other uses. But, as the (administrative) law also contained stipulations that enabled the lifting of these collective rights, it was clearly geared to the disappearance of the [page 11] commons.[3]
The authoritarian regime which reformulated the Civil Code in 1966 was brought down in 1974 by a military take-over. One of the coup’s effects was the restoration of the commons. Although the concept of common property did not return to the Civil Code, it was implicitly re-created by certain articles in the new constitution which defined the types of property legally existing in the country, and by a special decree, Decreto-Lei 39/76. This ‘law of the baldios’ reinstated community control over the commons. As most of the commons had been afforested by the State during the previous period, it also formulated guidelines for the new relation between the commoners and the State Forestry Service.
Decree 39/76 prescribed how villages should organize themselves to regain control over their communal Land and the revenues from the forests on them. Among other things, the law required an inventory to be made of entitlements and of entitled individuals. The latter were thought to be the ‘members’ of the community owning the baldio. The administration of the commons was attributed to a body elected by the members’ general assembly, the conselho directivo, or management committee. Recognition of the management committee by the State Forestry Service was a precondition for the initiation of the process of transfer of the land by the Service to the community. Thus the factual establishment of a common was made dependent on State approval. Consequently such establishment could become the outcome of a complicated interplay between the Forestry Service and different sections within a village community. (For a further description of some cases, see Brouwer 1995b: 213-222, 245-251. The law was revised in 1993.)
What’s in a Name? The Significance of a Signifier
The legal term for communal land differs from the term used by the general population. Whereas the population speaks of monte, lawyers and administrators use the word baldio. In Portuguese the word baldio literally means ‘naked’ or ‘uncultivated’ and is etymologically akin to the Arabic word baladi or to be bald (JCI 1939: 1; Velozo 1953: 23; Castro 1971; Soares 1968; Rodrigues 1987: 18; [page 12] Gralheiro 1990: 20; see also Vassberg 1975: 631-632, for the use of the word baidlo in Spain). The use of a word meaning ‘uncultivated’ for common property is connected to a confusion of the use of a certain area and its property status. Communal land is equated with waste land. This conflation of communal and waste land is misleading. Historical evidence indicates that the qualification of the commons as waste land, suggesting that the land was unused and, hence, available for other forms of exploitation and for other users, was incorrect. The commons served as pastures and were also used as outfields from which farmers collected the brush they used to fertilize their cultivated infields (Taborda 1932: 99, 111; Nunes and FeijO 1990). According to 1985 statistics, 70% of all uncultivated grounds (approximately one million ha) are privately owned; whereas, as a result of State afforestation efforts, 75% of the haldios (circa 380,000 ha) are actually covered by tbrests! Apparently, the legal status of land cannot be deduced from ecology and vegetation.
The use of the term baidlo in law has a specific significance. It expresses the legislators’ or the State’s perspective on these areas: they were waste lands, without any use or utility, and hence available for reclamation. Thus the use of this concept coincided with the State’s ambition to develop these lands through reclamation for agriculture or for forestry.
The redefinition of the commons in terms of res universitatis has a similar background. The way in which the concept of the commons was translated into a legal text has a specific relevance which can be grasped by perceiving law as a way of portraying or mapping normative structures. Like geographic maps, laws can be drawn in different ways, according to different methods of projections, on different scales, and with different symbols (Santos 1987). The projection method applied in the distinction between res communes, res publicae, res universitatis and res particulares is the hierarchy in the State. These categories refer to different, ranked social aggregates on different ‘scales’ that correspond to levels within the state apparatus. Individuals are not aggregated in families, village communities, or professional categories, but rather in the administrative units of the parish, the municipality (res u.niversitatis), or the State itself (res publicae). The inevitable consequence of this type of projection is the concealment of certain features of social reality outside the State’s administrative order which might also be important for the mapping of the normative structures that govern the use of land. In a manner similar to that of ordinary Mercator maps, where Africa appears deformed and smaller in relation to Europe than it is in reality, the niethod of projection chosen in the 1867 Civil Code disfigured or obscured forms of social organization that diverged from the hierarchy of levels in the State. Such deformations are not accidental. The general use of the Mercator projection is certainly the result of the metropolitan view of the world [page 13] expressed in it (Woods 1993: 57-61).[4] Similarly, the distortions and incongruities in legal maps are related to certain societal conditions, like the power of the State. The confusion in the 1867 Civil Code of community property with municipal or parish property facilitated the dissolution of community control over the baldios, and in doing so reflected the attempts to impose State control on the community and dissolve or take away the commons.
The baldio forms an example of the importance of names (labels) in legal discourse: commons are renamed waste lands so as to pennit the implementation of a centrally designed development policy. Renaming thus also is an act of appropriation: even without directly changing formal property rights, the new label prepares terrain for what is going to follow, namely, the dissolution of communal property rights. Finally, the case confirms a point made iii the introduction: property and its categories are not self-evident, but emerge in a strategic way. Beneath the simple notion of ‘common’ is hidden an amalgam of different arrangements of tenure and use.
The use of baldio as a term for communal land has a specific political meaning. A similar point can be made about the use of the word commons. The emphasis on the role of community control and the neglect of individual claims or rights from larger entities such as the State reflects the attempt to present common property regimes as a socially and ecologically desirable alternative to private and state property in resources.
The baldio case is not unique. It represents an example of a more widespread phenomenon of central governments trying to wrest control over resources from subject communities. On many occasions and in many places, States consume in an act of legal cannibalism nonnative frameworks formulated within subjugated entities which existed before the state. So did for example the colonial powers in their overseas domiions in Africa and Asia (Migot-Adholla and Bruce 1994; Mamdani 1995; Li 1996: 516; Juma and Ojwang 1996; Simbolon 1998). In Mozambique, for instance, the 1944 land law declared all land to be the property of the State and available for reclamation (Mozambique 1944). In Indonesia, all land which has no individual title falls within the definition of state land; the 1967 Forestry Law considers all people living in state forests without individual titles to be squatters (Li 1996: 516).
[page 14]
One issue raised in the introduction regarding the concept of property remained largely outside the discussion: that is, the function of law and its different idioms as a language in social interaction. The next case study of a conflict between two communities over a piece of land will elucidate this aspect of law.
Vila Verde Versus Parada de Pinhão
Some twenty kilometres from Vila Real on the road to the east lie Balsa and Vale de Agodim, two hamlets in the parish of Vila Verde in the municipality of AlijO. In 1989, the village populations of these hamlets created a joint management committee for their commons according to the rules defined by the 1976 decree on the baldios. The initiative received broad support. The constituent assembly was attended by 86 of the 102 commoners. The committee was immediately recognized by the local forestry administrator.
The objective of management committees is normally to manage the village commons and its revenues. However, in this particular case its prime objective was to win a court case against the parish council of neighbouring Parada de Pinhão, in the municipality of Sabrosa. When the case was won, the committee would immediately be dissolved and the commons handed over to the parish. The case was brought to court in AlijO in late 1989 or early 1990. According to the villagers, that parish had illegally claimed 338 ha of ‘baldia land’ and its revenues (for the situation of the villages and the disputed tracts, see the map, Figure 1). As one can read in the trial record, they demanded
that the defendant be condemned to recognize that the disputed lands are commons of the villages of Balsa and Vale de Agodim, of the parish of Vila Verde, and that these consequently belong to and are owned and used, and the usufructuary rights in them exercised by the plaintiff, the commoners’ assembly, to whom they were restored in terms of art° 30 of law 39/76 of the 19th of January (Alijó Court n.d; my translation).
The court case was the last battle in a protracted war that had been triggered by two incidents. The first occurred some time in the late 1970s and can be seen as one of the many unintended consequences of the 1974 revolution. That revolution led towards the restitution of the commons. It also profoundly changed the country’s internal political structure and its relationship with the outside world. It brought parliamentary democracy, opened the doors to EEC membership, and triggered a rapid decolonization of Portugal’s African provinces, Cape Verde, Guinea Bissau, Angola, and Mozambique. During the [page 15] 1950s and 1960s the Portuguese government had actively promoted migration to these territories. When in 1975-1976 the colonies gained independence, about 400,000 to 800,000 colonists returned to the motherland (Serrao 1985: 1001).
One of these returning colonists was Mr Salgueiro from Balsa.[5] Like many of his fellows he had to build a new home. For the construction of the roof he needed timber. As there were pines growing on the village commons, he thought it would be unnecessary to purchase timber and asked his fellow-villagers what [page 16] he had to do to obtain it. They told him that he should ask permission from the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhão, across the Pinhão River. Normally permission would be granted without any difficulty. They also told him that of course nobody would make a great fuss if he were to take the pines without authorization. Why bother to ask if it would be granted anyway? Salgueiro, however, decided that it was more appropriate to ask the council president for permission. If it was true that he would receive the pines, why should he not respect law and authority and ask for them as procedure demanded? Just as he expected, the president told him that it would be all right. He only asked Salgueiro to wait until the trees had been resinated. It would be a waste to cut a tree without taking its resin first. Salgueiro agreed and waited.
In the mean time two things happened. First, the parish priest of Parada de Pinhão, worried about the dilapidated condition of the chapel and its precinct which were the destinations of an annual pilgrimage, decided to raise funds for the sanctuary’s improvement. The parish council sympathized with the idea and agreed to sell some of its timber. Trees were cut in several areas, not only within the parish of Parada de PinhAo itself, but also in some of the stretches east of the river, in Vila Verde. The people of Balsa and Vale de Agodirn did not object to these fellings because the revenues were to be spent on the church. Second, after elections in Parda de Pinho, a new parish council took office. When Salgueiro went to see the new president, the latter bluntly refused permission saying that he would never again give any pine to anyone. Salgueiro was enraged, especially since that parish council had just cleared several high quality tree stands and made a substantial amount of money from the timber growing on the land belonging to his hamlet. Without the pines he had no choice hut to alter the plan for his house and make a concrete roof. But from then on, relations between Salgueiro and the parish council of Parada de Pinhão were deeply disturbed. He started to ask himself how it was possible that outsiders from Parada de Pinhão could freely dispose of the pines growing in the parish of Vila Verde, whereas he, an inhabitant of the parish, did not get what he was entitled to. Salgueiro resolved to investigate the background of this strange situation and to disclose his results to officials. He even wrote to the prime minister (interview 21 October 1990).[6]
[page 17]
The second incident dates from 1984. On 27 February of that year the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhão announced the public sale of some of its trees in a local newspaper, A Vôz de Trás-os-Montes. Although the advertisement did not refer to any trees standing on territory outside the parish, it soon appeared that some of the areas near Balsa and Vale de Agodim, east of the river, were included as well. As the trees were to be resinated before felling, a man came to the area in order to prepare resin collection and people soon became aware of what was happening. They contacted the Parish Council of Vila Verde, because they thought that it would be the right institution to defend the land against further intrusions. The Parish Council had the duty of representing the people of Vila Verde. Moreover, being the owner of the disputed areas and forests to defend the land and the trees on it was in its own interests. Pressured by the population, the Parish Council brought the case to court and sued its homologue of Parada de Pinhão in March 1985, claiming that the disputed land belonged to the property of the civil parish of Vila Verde.
But apparently the Vila Verde Parish Council was not very eager to pursue the action. It needed to present the names and signatures of individuals who would testify that the grounds truly belonged to Balsa and Vale de Agodim before a certain date. About twenty people from these hamlets offered to give evidence and defend their case. Salgueiro and another man, Morgado, who had also become engaged in the conflict, gathered the signatures and photocopies of the identity cards that the court required and handed these to Lopes, the president of the Parish Council, who promised to deliver them to the court house in Alijó. Some time later during a visit to Alijó, Salgueiro and Morgado ran into a court clerk who asked them whether they had abandoned their claim. He told them that the judges had not yet received the names and signatures of the witnesses and therefore intended to drop the case. The men were surprised and hurried to the town hall to ask the president of the municipality what was going on. There, they were soothed and told that everything would be all right (interview 21 October 1990). However, in January 1989, the people of the hamlets were surprised by the news that the parties had arrived at a compromise agreement and that the case had been dismissed. Vila Verde agreed to accept the property rights of Parada de Pinhão over the baldios of Lameirões, Luvetia, and Esteval (338 ha; A, B and C in figure 1), whereas Parada de Pinhão acknowledged the [page 18] rights of Vila Verde over the areas of Ervedeira and Castelhano (141 ha; D in figure 1) (Alijó Court n.d).
The inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim were astounded by the compromise and felt betrayed by their own representatives, who had handed over most of the contested area to the enemy without even consulting them. The people’s leaders, Morgado and Salgueiro, met and decided to continue the war in order to recover the land surrendered by Parish Council of Vila Verde by using a new weapon. They went to the Communist Party for advice, ‘because the communists know how to act in this kind of affairs.’ The Communist Party brought them into contact with another organization, the secretariat of the commons’ management committees in Vila Real.[7] The man in charge of this body told them that if they really wanted to claim the commons of their villages, they should create a management committee. That committee would be able to claim ownership of the commons in terms of the 1976 bill against both the Parish Councils of Vila Verde and Parada de Pinhão. Furthermore, he introduced them to Jaime Gralheiro, a lawyer who was a specialist in common property matters and an author of an extensive commentary on the baldios laws (Graiheiro 1990). The lawyer agreed to take up the affair and presented it again in court in Alijó.
According to the villagers, the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhão has again since then tried to rob them of their property. In January 1990, a lumberjack appeared who had bought trees in the Balsa/Vale de Agodim area from the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhão. The population was furious and blocked the road. They stopped the police, who had been sent by the authorities to protect him, elsewhere. Salgueiro went to talk to the lumberjack and explained to him that the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhâo had sold him something which it did not own, and the best thing he could do was to return to Parada de Pinhão and ask for his money back. A forest guard who arrived at the scene also intervened. The Parish Council did not have permission to fell the trees and, as they were not yet fully grown, the guard refused to issue a licence (interview 21 October 1990).
The case of Balsa and Vale de Agodim remained pending in court until October 1993, when, for the time being at least, the conflict was settled by mutual agreement between the parties. Parada de Pinhão recognized the claims of Balsa [page 19] and Vale de Agodim to most of the baldios. The people from the hamlets acknowledged that the commons lying between the Pinhão River and the road connecting Balsa to Vilar de Macada belonged to the population of Parada de Pinhão. Finally, it was agreed that the Serra das Lameiras baldios would be split and the border would be marked by a firebreak (Alijó Court n.d).
The Commons as Private Property
The conflict between the parish council of Parada de Pinhao and the people of Balsa and Vale de Agodim can be read as an exchange of fire in a war, or, in a less colourilil way, as an exchange of phrases in different languages and idioms, a discourse (Geertz 1973). The event in itself may interest the reader as a picturesque story of a rural conflict. From a sociological perspective, however, it is merely a starting point fhr analysis. Questions arise about motives and the forms of legitimation invoked by the different parties and about the way in which they used different means (concrete actions, legal idioms) in their efforts to achieve their aims.
The first step on the road to a more complete understanding of the case is to recognise that underneath the bare question of ownership presented to court - who was the rightful master of the disputed pieces of land - lay another issue. That was the existence of different descriptions of the legal status of the land, of different labels and contents of the word property. The Parada de Pinhão parish council argued that the land was its private property (dominium plenum). It produced a document of 1892 which listed the disputed areas among a series of properties which had been acquired by Joaquim Pedro Miller from the Count of Sampaio and had been sold by his daughter Guilhermina Magelhães Miller and his other heirs to the parish council of Parada de Pinhão. In the 1930s the central State land reclamation and forestry agencies had accepted this document as proof that the grounds were not baldios, i.e. waste lands, but part of the property of the parish council. For that reason, they had refrained from dividing and afforesting the land (JCI 1939: 304-305).
Initially the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim were inclined to accept this argument. However, they argued that, if the Sainpaio/Miller estate had become the property of the parish, the parts of that estate lying east of the river were the property of the Vila Verde parish. In the past, the hamlets and the surrounding land east of the Pinhão River had been part of Parada de Pinhão. Later, the territory had been detached and transferred to Vila Verde. As a natural consequence of this administrative division, the estates of the parish council also had to be partitioned. In such cases, the partition is made on the basis of the new geographical division. Thus, together with the villages the parish properties lying [page 20] to the east of the river were legally transferred to the parish council of Vila Verde.
The idea that the land belonged to the parish council of Vila Verde emerged during and as a result of the conflict. Until then the villagers had accepted that the Parada de Pinhão parish council exercised some control over these tracts. They had accepted this because the new administrative division had no influence on the villagers’ daily life. The inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim hardly noticed any difference. Ecclesiastically, the separation was never implemented: the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim continued to go to mass in Parada de Pinhão, to pay their côngrua (an annual ecclesiastical tax) to the priest there, and, when they died, to be buried in the graveyard of that parish (Alijó Court n.d). The parish council of Vila Verde hardly ever interfered in the hamlets’ internal affairs. Thus, the inhabitants hardly noticed and rapidly came to ignore the new administrative order. People living in Balsa and Vale de Agodim used their commons as they had always done. Because in the past the Parada de Pinhão parish council had had a say in management of the commons, the people of Balsa and Vale de Agodim continued to ask permission to engage in particular forms of exploitation, especially the cutting of wood. The ‘normality’ of this regulation was challenged only when the population thought that the council was abusing its privilege (interview 21 October 1990). That challenge even then did not at first relate to the property status of the land: the villagers continued to see it as parish property.
In the light of the description of the land as private parish property it was natural that the villagers turned to their parish council in Vila Verde. However, as the Vila Verde Parish Council betrayed their interests, they decided to change the argument and look for another juridical description. This they found in the 1976 law on the commons. By creating a commoners’ assembly and electing a management committee, they established grounds to describe the disputed areas as common property. Of course this description was not entirely imaginary; it was based on the exploitation of the land as a common pool resource for brush, the! wood and pasture. According to the villagers there had been several herds, seven in Balsa and five in Vale de Agodim. As a result of general social and economic development, pasturage had declined. The number of animal heads decreased sharply because of the mass migration of young and able men to North-Western Europe, Brazil, and the African territories. As a result, since the sixties the land had been covered spontaneously by a pine forest (Alijó Court n.d). In Balsa, today nobody has cattle which they can take to graze on the commons, but in Vale de Agodim some have. There, people still have some 70 to 80 sheep and goats, and many more cows (interview 21 October 1990).
The villagers also acknowledged that inhabitants from across the river exercised [page 21] certain rights an the disputed lands. However, they denied that these rights were part of a ‘bundle’ of rights held by the Parada de Pinhäor parish council over these areas. Instead, they argued that these rights had a different origin. In part they were the individual rights of certain inhabitants of Parada de Pinhâo. People from Parada de Pinhâo owning land on the east bank of the river were entitled to collect brush on the commons on that side to fertilize those fields as a kind of extension of their private property rights. They however did not hold grazing rights. In addition, the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim collectively paid the Parada de Pinhâo parish priest their annual religious fees or cóngruas by selling each three or four years some strips of brush of the common called Esteval. But this money was given to the Church, and not to the Parish Council, and hence did not reflect or confirm any property rights of that body. This tradition explains also why in 1980 or 1981 the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodini had accepted the sale and cutting of pines by the parish council of Parada de Pinhâo: they had been told that the money was to be used to repair the sanctuary (Alijó Court n.d).
The question about the property status of the disputed tracts underlay the court case. Different assertions about that Status were made during the process. However, it was only one of the issues brought up by the parties. Both lawyers did their utmost to put forward nice legal arguments. The defendant’s lawyer suggested for instance that the management committee had no capacity to sue, on the ground that it was a mere aggregate of people administering a common land but not an incorporated legal person. He claimed also that the litigation was a res judicata and should be dismissed on the ground that the Parish Council of Vila Verde had litigated over the same claim in 1985, and the settlement then agreed to by both parties had been confirmed by the court. When in October 1990 both objections were rejected, Parada de Pinhão appealed to the Court of Appeal in Porto, but without success.
The plaintiff’s lawyer went so far as to contest the very existence of the Count of Sampaio and Guilemina Magelhâes Miller. He also disputed the property claim by Parada de Pinhâo on the basis of the contract of sale of 1892. That contract referred to the sale not of property but of the dominium directum, the paramount ownership of a lord, as distinguished from that of his vassal holding the dominium util. These paramount ownership rights were extremely limited as they concerned only the payment of rents by the user, who was completely free to use the land as he wanted or to alienate it (Van den Bergh 1988). During the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries these rights which stemmed from the feudal legal system were abolished. Therefore, the plaintiff argued, today the contract put forward by Parada de Pinhâo to sustain its ownership rights was completely worthless.
[page 22]
Both parties also made opposing claims about the factual exploitation of forest in the disputed areas. Parada de Pinhäo asserted that it had exploited the areas for over 50 years by the collection resin and the felling of trees. The villagers affirmed that the actual forest was the result of spontaneous regeneration and not of human interference, and that it had not been used on a regular basis. Totally at a loss, the court sought an appraisal by experts. They concluded that two areas of the forest must have had a spontaneous origin, probably following on a decline in grazing. In other parts they found signs of exploitation dating from the period between 1960 and 1972, sustaining the allegations made by Parada de Piithäo.
Historical Roots: Phantoms from the Past
The administrative reforms of the nineteenth century, mentioned above, in which the hamlets of Balsa and Vale de Agodim were detached from Parada de Pinhão and transferred to Vila Verde, would perhaps not have caused so many problems had they been carried out in a straightforward manner. But for almost fifty years the hamlets were in a vague position. In 1855 they were administratively separated from Parada de Pinhão, that was part of the municipality of Sabrosa. However, for religious affairs, the inhabitants remained dependent on that parish. Only civil affairs had to be dealt with in Vila Verde. This situation was particularly confusing as at that time State and Church had not been separated and the Church exercised certain civil functions such as the registration of births, marriages and deaths. A reform of 1878 did not fully solve the problem: the hamlets of Balsa and Vale de Agodim were returned to the parish of Parada de Pinhão for both their religious and their administrative affairs, but they remained in the municipality of Alijó. Only in 1913 was the natural effect of the 1855 division finally consummated: the hamlets were separated from their parish on die west side of the Pinhão River and included in Vila Verde on the east (Diário do Governo, 7 August 1913). In religion the villagers remained dependent upon the parish west of the river, but since Church and State had finally been separated in 1911, this had no civil effect.
In addition to this intricate process of administrative division and the incomplete separation of Church and State, the case has another historical root. In the past the hamlets of Balsa and Vale de Agodim had been single farms. They had never been recognized as independent village communities or povos. Under the legal system that preceded the 1867 Civil Code, povos had a specific status. Although dependent upon the municipal courts and administration, they were authorised to deal with minor offences, and also maintained a certain administrative autonomy. To become a povo, a village had to consist of at least twenty households and be situated over ten to twelve kilometres from a town with a court house [page 23] Ordenações Filipinas I, Titulo IX, nº 73). Parada de Pinhão had been an independent fief (honra) of the Counts of Sampaio and the major town in the area. Balsa and Vale de Agodim were too small and too close to Parada de Pinhão to be made povos and their inhabitants had been filly dependent on the juridical and administrative systems of that town. This past still influences today’s attitudes. The inhabitants of Parada de Pinhão see the people from Balsa and Vale de Agodim as ‘uncivilized boors’ and treat them as such. As the villagers put it: “In the eyes of the people from Parada de Pinhão, we are even less than the dogs that they keep to guard their farms” (interview 21 October 1990). The present conflict was a kind of revenge or, as the son of the Parada de Pinhão parish president put it to the dismay of his father, “au attempt by both hamlets to emancipate themselves and become independent” (interview 21 October 1994).
Medieval rules about the political status of communities, a nineteenth century administrative division, and the relatively late secularization of the Portuguese states explain the emergence of this conflict. But they are not the only phantoms of the past that disturb today’s peace. The peoples of Vila Verde and Parada de Pinhão are also haunted by ancient concepts of property that, although officially dead and buried, continue to exercise power today. On the basis of a contract of sale of 1892 the parish council of Parade de Pinhão argued that the land was the private property of the parish. It also acknowledged that it had been exploited communally by the parishioners, and so, in eighteenth century terms, described the land as a maninho. The villagers agreed that the land probably had not been a ‘true’ baldio as defined by Tomaz Vila Nova de Portugal, but they claimed that that description was valid today. They argued that, because of the abolition of feudal rights, the land had become baldio, a ‘real’ common.
Conclusion
The question raised at the beginning of this paper concerned the way in which property is dealt with in the common property-rights debate. It was argued that in most of the literature property is treated superficially. The historical contingency of different resource-use rights is hardly acknowledged. Instead, the discussion limits itself to a simple categorization of property regimes along the lines open access, state, common and private• property. It is proposed that a more complete understanding of common property arrangements requires a more detailed or ‘thick’ analysis of concrete common property-like situations, which will expose the different underlying structures of production, perception and interpretation of social action.
This paper shows that such a ‘thick’ analysis of a concrete case does indeed lead [page 24] towards new understandings. A ‘thin’ reading of the case between the two groups, the villagers of Balsa and Vale de Agodim in the parish of Vila Verde, and the Parish Council of Parada de Pinhão, would probably have resulted in a simplified image of the situation. It would have appeared that the village communities were fighting for the restitution of what had been unlawfully seized from them by the local State, which merely wanted to make easy profits by selling the timber and resin. My reading of the events leads to a very different conclusion. According to this, baldio appears as one of the labels that can possibly be tagged to the disputed areas. That, for the time being, and for most of the area, it is the ‘winning’ label, is a result of the different factors that structure the ‘dialogue’ between the parties.
As the analysis of the events has shown, the application of the baldio label is contingent on many factors. The first is the collapse of existing use regulations in the semi-autonomous field consisting of the main proponents of the conflict, the parish councils of Parada de Pinhâo and Vila Verde, and the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim. This collapse was brought about by the fact that one of the field’s members, a relative outsider, who was dissatisfied with the functioning of the field, started to question the legitimacy of the arrangements. It resulted in the recognition that the land had a legal status and that this status might be disputed. The historically changing legal framework, from which different descriptions and idioms could be taken, strategic alliances in and outside the legal field, and, last but not least, a deeply-rooted complex of inferiority among the inhabitants of Balsa and Vale de Agodim in their relation with Parada de Pinhão structure the evolution of the conflict and its outcome, the creation and official acknowledgement of a common covering a large part of the disputed areas.
Finally, the baldio label itself can be questioned. It appears that it has a twin brother, tnonte. Monte is the word used by the population to refer to communally used open woody vegetation, whereas baldio stems from the State’s legal and administrative idiom and expresses the State’s desire to appropriate and reclaim these lands.
The various labels for the commons in Portugal refer to different idioms, different political ambitions and different relations between private and communal use entitlements. The use of these labels is politically meaningful as it is part of the ‘dialogue’ between the different stakeholders in the commons. The implication is clear. ‘Commons’ cannot be taken for granted even if they have an official legal basis. If indeed many contributions to the debate on common property-rights regimes are ‘thin’ and based on ‘overarching’ models of property, it is urgently necessary to revise much of the debate which has taken place so far, in order to establish what the ‘commons’ referred to really are. It is obvious that a thorough analysis of the legal basis of these commons and the way in which this basis is developed within social struggles will constitute an important contribution to such a reappraisal.
References
ACHESON, James M.
1988 The Lobster Gangs of Maine. Portland, Maine: University
Press of
New England.
1994 ‘Welcome to Nobel country: an overview of institutional
economics.’
Pp. 3-18 in James M. Acheson (ed.) Anthropology and Institutional
Economics, Monographs in Economic Anthropology 12. Lanham/New
York/London: University Press of America.
ALIJÓ COURT
n.d.
Aljó Dossier, record kept by the court of Alijó with respect to the
cases Parish Council of Vita Verde v Parish Council of Parada de
Pinhão and Commoners’ Management Committee of the Baldios of
Balsa and Vale de Agodim (Parish of Vila Verde) v Parish Council of
Parada de Pinhão (Alijó Courthouse).
BAUER, Dan
1987 ‘The dynamics of communal and hereditary land tenure among the
Tigray of Ethiopia.’ Pp. 217-230 in Bonnie M. McCay and James
M. Acheson (eds.) The Question of the Commons. The Culture and
Ecology of Communal Resources. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
BENDA-BECKMANN, Franz von
1991 ‘Legal uncertainty in land management.’ In H. Savenije and A.
Huijsmnan (eds.) Making Haste Slowly. Strengthening Local Environmental
Management in Agricultural Development. Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute.
1992 ‘Introduction.’ Pp. 1-22 in Franz von Benda-Beckmami and Menno
van der Velde (eds.) Law as a Resource in Agrarian Struggles.
Wageningen: Agricultural University.
1995 ‘Property Rights and Common Resources’, presented at the congress ‘Agrarian Questions; the politics of fanning anno 1995’, Wageningen, 22-24 May. Pp. 54-85 in Conference Proceedings, Vol. One.
BENDA-BECKMANN, Keebet von
1981 ‘Forum shopping and shopping tbrums: dispute settlement in a
Minangkabau village in West Sumatra.’ Journal of Legal Pluralism
19: 117-159.
BERKES, Fikret
1996 ‘Social Systems, Ecological Systems and Property Rights.’ Pp. 87-
107 in Hanna et al.
BERKES, F., D. FEENY, Bonnie J. McCAY and James M. ACHESON
1989 ‘The benefits of the commons.’ Nature 340: 91-93.
BOHANNAN, Paul (ed.)
1967 Law and Warfare. Studies in the Anthropology of Conflict.
Garden
City, New York: The Natural History Press.
BROMLEY, Daniel W.
1992 ‘The commons, property, and common-property regimes.’ Pp. 3-15
in Daniel W. Bromley (ed.), Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice, and
Policy. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.
BROUWER, Roland
1992 ‘The commons in Portugal: a story of static representations and
dynamic social processes.’ Pp. 127-148 in Franz von Benda Beckman and Menno van
der Velde (eds.) Law as a Resource in Agrarian Struggles.
Wageningen: Agricultural University.
1995a 'Common goods and private profits: traditional and modern communal land management in Portugal.’ Human Organization 54: 283-294.
1995b Planting Power. The Afforestation of the Commons and State Formation in Portugal. DeIft: Eburon.
CAETANO, Marcello
1991 Manual do Direito Administrativo, 10th ed. Coimbra: Almedina.
CASTRO, Armando de
1971 ‘Baldios.’ Pp. 277-282 in Joel Serrão (org.), Diccionário
Histórico de
Portugal. Lisboa: Iniciativas Editoriais.
CHANOCK, Martin
1982 ‘Making customary law: man, women, and courts in colonial Northern Rhodesia.’ Pp. 53-67 in Margaret Jean Hay and Marcia Wright (eds.) African Women and the Law: Historical Perspectives, Boston University Papers on Africa, VII. Boston, Massachusetts: Boston University.
COX, Susan Jane Buck
1985 ‘No tragedy of the commons.’ Environmental Ethics 7: 49-61.
DEVY-VARETA, Nicole
1993 A Floresta no Espaço e no Tempo em Portugal. A Arborização da Serra da Cabreira (1919-1975), Ph.D. thesis. Porto: University of Porto.
DIAS, Jorge
1983 Vilarinho da Furna. Uma Aldeia Communitária. Lisbon: Imprensa Nacional/Casa de Moeda.
1984 Rio de Onor. Cornunitarismo Agro-Pastoril. Lisbon: Ediciio Presença.
FEENY, D., F. BERKES, Bonnie J. MCCAY and James M. ACHESON
1990 ‘The tragedy of the commons: twenty-two years later.’ Human Ecology 18: 1-19.
GALANTER, Marc
1981 ‘Justice in many rooms: courts, private ordering, and indigenous law.’ Journal of Legal Pluralism 19: 1-47.
GALILEA, Pedro
1998 ‘The unsuccessful privatization of common property in Spain: forest and pastures in Galicia (a law and economics perspective)’, presented at the Seventh Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property. Vancouver, June 10-14.
GEERTZ, Clifford
1973 The Interpretation of Cultures. Selected Essays. New York: Basic Books.
GLASER, Barney G. and Anselm L. STRAUSS
1967 The Discovery of Grounded Theory. Strategies for Qualitative Research. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.
GLUCKMAN, Max (ed.)
1969 Ideas and Procedures in African Customary Law. Oxford: OUP.
GRALHEIRO, Jaime
1990 Commentário à(s) Lei(s) dos Baldios. Coimbra: Livraria Almedina.
GRIFFITHS, John
1986 ‘What is Legal Pluralism?’ Journal of Legal Pluralism 24: 1-55.
1991 Legal Pluralism and the Social Working of Law. Groningen: University of Groningen. Mimeo.
HANNA, Susan, Carl FOLK€ and Karl-GOran MALER
1996 ‘Property rights and the natural environment,’ Pp. 1-10 in Hanna et al.
HANNA. Susan, Carl FOLKE and Karl-Göran MALER (eds.)
1996 Rights to Nature. Ecological, Economic, Cultural, and Political Principles of Institutions for the Environment. Washington DC: Island Press.
HARDIN, Garrett
1968 ‘The tragedy of the commons.’ Science 162: 1243-1248.
1979 ‘Why plant a redwood tree?’ In G.T. Miller (ed.) Living in the environment. Belmont: Wadsworth.
HESPANHA, António Manuel
1980 ‘0 juristo e o legislador na construção do propriedade burgesa liberal em Portugal.’ Análise Social 61/62: 211-236.
JESSOP, Bob
1983 The Capitalist State. London: Basil Blackwell.
JODHA, Narpat S.
1996 ‘Property rights and development.’ Pp. 205-220 in Hanna et al.
JCI (Junta da Colonizacao Interna)
1939 Reconhecimento dos Baldios do ontinente. Lisboa; Ministério de Agricultura.
JUMA, Calestous and Jackton B. Ojwang (eds.)
1996 In Land We Trust. Environment, Private Property and Constitutional change. Nairobi, Kenya/London, UK: Initiatives Publishers, Zed Books.
LI, Tania Murray
1996 ‘Images of community: discourse and strategy in property relations.’ Development and Change 27: 501-527.
MAMDANI, Mahmood
1995 ‘Indirect rule, civil society and ethnicity: the African dilemma’, background paper for congress ‘Agrarian Questions; the politics of farming anno 1995.’ Wageningen, 22-24 May 1995.
McCAY, J. Bonnie
1996 ‘Common and private concerns.’ Pp. 111-126 in Hanna et ul.
McCAY, Bonnie M. and James M. ACHESON (eds.)
1987 The Question of the c’ommons. The Culture and Ecology of Communal Resources. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
McCAY, Bonnie and Svein JENTOFT
1998 ‘Market or community failure? Critical perspectives on common property research.’ Human Organization 57: 21-29.
MERRY, Sally Engle
1988 ‘Legal Pluralism.’ Law and Society Review 22: 869-896.
MIGOT-ADHOLLA, Shem E. and John W. BRUCE
1994 ‘Introduction: are indigenous African systems insecure’?’ Pp. 1-11 in John Bruce and Shein B. Migot-Adholla (eds.) Searching for Land Tenure Security in Africa. Dubuque, Iowa: Kendall Hunt.
MOORE, Sally Falk
1973 ‘Law and social change: the semi-autonomous social field as an appropriate subject of study.’ Law and Society Review 7: 719-746.
1978 Law as Process: An Anthropological Approach. London and Boston, Massachusetts: Routledge and Keegan Paul.
MOZAMBIQUE
1944 Decree 33,727 of 22 June 1944. Boletim Oficial 40, I Serie, Suplement, 6 October 1944.
NELKEN, David
1981 ‘The “gap” problem in the sociology of law: a theoretical review.’ Windsor Yearbooak of Access to Justice: 35-61.
NEVES, Carlos Manuel Beata
1964 ‘Nas vésperas da comemoração duma data célebra, o I Centenário da Fundação do Ensino Superior Florestal’, separata da Gazeta das Aldeias 2532.
NUNES, João Arriscado and Rui Graça FEIJÓ
1990 ‘As Transformaçães dos “Incultus” no Noroeste (1750-1900). Uma Proposta de Reapreciação,’ Cadernos de Ciências Sociais 8/9: 45-90.
OSTROM. Elinor
1990 Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Actions. Cambridge, Britain: Cambridge University Press.
OSTROM, Elinor and Edella SCHLAGER
1996 ‘The Formation of Property Rights.’ Pp. 127-156 in Hanna et al.
PAIXÁO, J. da Silva, J. Aregão SEIA, and C.A. Fernandez CADILHA
1983 Código Administrativo, Actualizado e Anotado. Legislação Complementar. Coimbra: Almedina.
POSPISIL, Leopold
1967 ‘The Attributes of Law.’ Pp. 25-41 in Paul Bohannan (ed.), Law and Warfare. Studies in the Anthropology of Conflict Garden City, New York: The Natural History Press.
1971 Anthropology of Law. A Comparative Theory. New York, etc: Harper & Row.
RIBEIRO, Orlando
1991 Opúsculos Geográficos. Volume IV. 0 Mundo Rural. Lisbon: Fundação Calouste Gulbenkian.
RODRIGUES, Manuel
1987 Os Baldios. Lisboa: Caminho.
SANTOS, Boaventura de Sousa
1987 ‘Law: A Map of Misreading. Towards a Postmodern Conception of Law,’ Journal of Law and Society 14: 279-302.
SERRAO, Joel
1985 ‘Notas sobre emigração e mudança no Portugal conteinporâneo.’ Análise Social 87/88/89: 995-1004.
SIMBOLON, Indira Juditka
1998 Peasant Women and Access to Land. Customary Law, State Law and Gender-Based Ideology. The Case of the Toha-Batak (North Sumatra). Ph.D. Thesis, Landbouw Universiteit Wageningen.
SOARES, Rogério Erhardt
1968 ‘Sobre os baldios.’ Separata of Revista de Direiro e Estudos Sociais 141(3/4).
SPIERTZ, H. Joep L.
1991 ‘The Transformation of Traditional Law: A Tale of People’s Participation in Irrigation Management on Bali.’ Landscape and Urban Planning 20: 199-196.
1992 ‘Between cannibalism and pluralism: on the construction of legal frameworks in irrigation management in Bali and Sri Lanka.’ Pp. 23-43 in Franz von Benda-Beckmann and Menno van der Velde (eds.), Law as a Resource in Agrarian Struggles. Wageningen: Agricultural University.
SPIERTZ, Joep and Melanie G. WIBER
1996 ‘The bull in the china shop. Regulation, property rights and natural resource management: an introduction.’ Pp. 1-15 in Joep Spiertz and Melanie G. Wiber (eds.), The Role of Law in Natural Resource Management. Amsterdam: B. Niemeyer.
TAB ORDA, Vergflio
1932 Alto Trás-os-Montes. Estudo Geogrdflco. Coimbra: Imprensa da Universidade.
TAMANAHA, Brian Z.
1993 ‘The Folly of the “Social Scientific” Concept of Legal Pluralism.’ Journal of Law and Society 20: 192-217.
VAN DEN BERGH, C.J.J.
1996 ‘Property versus ownership. Some cursory notes.’ Pp. 167-176 in Joep Spiertz and Melanie G. Wiber (eds.), The Role of Law in Natural Resource Management. Amsterdam: E. Niemeyer.
VASSBERG, David E.
1975 ‘The sale of terras baidlas in sixteenth-century Castile.’ Journal of Modern History 47: 629-654.
VELOZO, Francisco José
1953 ‘Baldios, maninhos e exploração silvo-pastoril em comum (estudo económico e jurídico),’ separata of nr. 10 of Volume III, pp. 123ff. of Scientia Juridica. Braga: Livraria Cruz.
WOODS, Denis
1993 The Power of Maps. London: Routledge.